Simone Balestra, Uschi Backes-Gellner, Heterogeneous returns to education over the wage distribution: who profits the most?, In: Swiss Leading House "Economics of Education" Working Paper, No. 91, 2013. (Working Paper)
 
|
|
Uschi Backes-Gellner, Shiho Futagami, Silvia Teuber, Andrea Willi, Differences in Initial Training and Wages of Japanese Engineering and Retailing Companies - Who Pays for Higher Training Costs?, In: Swiss Leading House "Economics of Education" Working Paper, No. 90, 2013. (Working Paper)
 
The optimal human resource and skill development strategy is one important factor of economic success. This paper, therefore, analyzes industry-specific differences in the training provision between engineering and retailing companies in Japan and focuses in particular on the initial training provision for intermediate skills at the firm level. Based on 11 in-depth interviews in the retailing and the engineering sector in Japan, we find that gross training costs per basic trainee are significantly higher in engineering than in retailing. However, not only the engineering companies, but also their employees bear higher costs than their counterparts in retailing. The absolute and relative entrance wages for production employees are significantly lower than the entrance wages of employees in sale. Even though wages in engineering increase significantly stronger within the first five years, the absolute and relative wages in engineering remain still significantly lower. The results relate to the qualification levels of new trainees and the career paths |
|
Jens Mohrenweiser, Thomas Zwick, Uschi Backes-Gellner, Poaching and Firm-sponsored Training: First Clean Evidence, In: ZEW Discussion Paper, No. 37, 2013. (Working Paper)
 
|
|
Christian Rupietta, Uschi Backes-Gellner, Combining knowledge stock and knowledge flow to generate superior incremental innovation performance - Evidence from Swiss manufacturing, In: Swiss Leading House "Economics of Education" Working Paper, No. 89, 2017. (Working Paper)
 
Firms generate new knowledge that leads to innovations by recombining existing knowledge sources. A successful recombination depends on the availability of a knowledge stock (human capital pool) and the flow of knowledge within the firm (induced by HRM systems). While human resource theory expects complementarities between human capital pools and HRM systems, it does not explicitly address how knowledge exchange may be guaranteed or fostered. Moreover, empirical approaches neglect the complexity of such complementarities. In this study we develop a model that integrates a firm’s knowledge stock and flow into a knowledge creation (KC) system comprising four ideal types. This system explains the occurrence of superior incremental innovation performance. We empirically analyze the KC system by applying fuzzy set qualitative comparative analysis (fsQCA) and identify configurations concurring with our ideal types. The results show that the use of human capital and HRM practices depends on firm size and industry dynamism. |
|
Uschi Backes-Gellner, Sara Brunner, Duale Berufsbildung wird unterschätzt - Akademiker starten nicht immer von der Poleposition, In: Swiss Leading House "Economics of Education" Working Paper, No. 84, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
|
|
Simon Janssen, Simone Tuor Sartore, Uschi Backes-Gellner, Social Norms and Firms' Discriminatory Pay-Setting, In: UZH Business Working Paper, No. 327, 2013. (Working Paper)
 
|
|
Uschi Backes-Gellner, Silvia Teuber, How do companies adapt their organization to national institutions: evidence from matched-pair engineering companies, In: Swiss Leading House "Economics of Education" Working Paper, No. 82, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
Companies face competitive advantages or disadvantages depending on a country’s national institutional setting. The question is whether and how companies with highly similar product markets and technologies are able to stay competitive if they are located in disadvantaged national institutional settings. Building on the Varieties of Capitalism approach, we analyze the effect of different national institutional settings on one important characteristic of a company’s organizational structure, the span of control of production supervisors. Through plant interviews, we generated a unique dataset of matched-pair engineering companies in Germany, Switzerland, the UK, and the U.S. The findings indicate that the span of control is an important mechanism of adjustment to national institutional settings. Production supervisors in companies producing in coherently coordinated market economy like Germany have on average a broader span of control than those in coherently liberal market economy like the U.S. However, in mixed institutional settings like Switzerland and the UK, we find companies with a broad and companies with a narrow span of control, thus indicating that companies have the strategic power to adjust with their own company-level institutions to either complementing or substituting national institutions. |
|
Robert Göx, Say on pay design, executive pay, and board dependence, In: SSRN, No. 1908592, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
I study the impact of ''say on pay'' (SoP) on the compensation decisions and the structure of the board of directors (BoD) in a setting where the CEO has the real authority over the composition of the BoD. The CEO's authority arises endogenously from an informational advantage about individual board members' contribution to firm value and allows her to establish a dependent BoD. Shareholders approve the CEO's director slate because they can only control the level of board dependence but not the board's contribution to firm value. In this setting, SoP has two effects. On the one hand, it prompts a BoD with a given dependence level to reduce the CEO's bonus. On the other hand, it allows the CEO to extract the rent generated by the improved compensation policy and to establish a more dependent BoD. In equilibrium the board becomes more dependent from the CEO and pays her a higher bonus for the same performance. This outcome can only be avoided if the CEO is restricted in her ability to adjust the board composition. Motivated by existing differences in SoP design, I also analyze the consequences of a binding and a pre-contractual vote. I find that a binding vote creates a moral hazard problem on the part of the firm's shareholders if the vote takes place after the agent has supplied her effort. Its consequences critically depend on the legal protection standard of the CEO. Whenever the shareholders can enforce a retroactive bonus cut, the allowable amount of the bonus reduction determines whether or not SoP improves the efficiency of the pay process or diminishes firm value. I show that the moral hazard problem can be avoided by a pre-contractual vote. If the vote is binding, SoP can improve the efficiency of the compensation arrangement and effectively reduce the equilibrium level of board dependence without impairing the CEO's effort incentives. |
|
Robert Göx, Frédéric Imhof, Alexis H Kunz, ‘Say on Pay’ design and its repercussion on CEO investment incentives, compensation, and firm profit, In: SSRN, No. 1588682, 2010. (Working Paper)
 
We conduct an experiment to study different shareholder voting right regimes in a setting where shareholders provide incentives to a CEO for a risky project choice through a discretionary bonus scheme. We compare three different types of shareholder voting rights (advisory, unconditionally binding, and conditionally binding voting rights) to the baseline case where shareholders have no say on CEO pay. We make the following observations: (1) Advisory and conditionally binding voting rights do not distort CEO investment incentives. Unconditionally binding voting rights adversely affect the CEO’s investment incentives. (2) Unconditionally binding voting rights are an effective instrument to curb executive compensation. Advisory shareholder voting rights have the opposite effect and can even increase executive compensation. (3) Most shareholders reject CEO bonus proposals whenever they have the right to do so. This effect is independent of the type of voting right in place and becomes more pronounced in case of poor project performance. (4) Advisory and conditionally binding voting rights have only limited impact on firm profit and executive compensation. In contrast, unconditionally binding voting rights reduce both, firm profit and executive compensation significantly. Overall, our results suggest that regulators should carefully evaluate dysfunctional economic consequences of shareholder voting rights before they are introduced or before existing rules are tightened. |
|
Robert Göx, Uwe Heller, The dual role of peer groups in executive pay: Relative performance evaluation versus benchmarking, In: Working papers / Faculty of Economic and Social Sciences, University of Fribourg, No. 402, 2008. (Working Paper)
 
We study the role of peer groups in determining the structure and the total amount of executive compensation. Our analysis is based on a standard agency model in which the agent's reservation utility is related to the peer group used for performance evaluation. Our main result is that the informativeness criterion proposed by Holmström (1979) is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for the optimality of a relative performance evaluation. Whenever the relative performance evaluation is positively related to the agent's reservation utility, the principal faces a trade-off between the benefits from improved risk sharing and the total cost of compensation. If the peer group effect is strong, it can be optimal to evaluate the agent on her own firm performance only. If the relative performance evaluation is negatively related to the agent's reservation utility, it can also prove useful to reward the agent on the basis of uninformative signals. We also study the optimal weighting and composition of the performance index and find that the principal puts lower (higher) weight on an index and on peer firms that are positively (negatively) related with agent's reservation utility. In case of a negative relation it can even be optimal to include firms with uncorrelated cash flows into the index in order to reduce the total compensation. |
|
Robert Göx, A performance comparison of strategic transfer pricing and tidy cost allocation in presence of product market competition and congestion costs, In: Social Science Research Network, No. 150598, 1999. (Working Paper)
 
This paper compares the performance of transfer pricing and tidy cost allocations in a multiproduct firm in presence of output market competition and production externalities. In absence of competition, tidy cost allocations are creating inefficient allocations within the firm while transfer prices can always be adjusted to replicate the first best solution of the centralized firm. While the second result is well known, the first result draws a parallel to the impossibility of solving the free rider problem in team production by a profit sharing scheme. Under duopolistic competition, transfer prices are still the best accounting rule but the solution depends on the nature of competition on the final product market. When firms compete in prices, the strategic rationale requires to allocate more than the total cost of the congested service to the duopolistic departments. While transfer prices can still be adjusted accordingly, the tidiness requirement prevents the cost allocation scheme from providing the desired strategic incentives to the firms' managers. Under quantity competition, the strategic motive requires to allocate less than the cost of the service to the duopolistic departments. Although a tidy cost allocation scheme does not contradict the required direction of the strategic effect, the optimal allocation is at best found incidentally while the transfer prices can again always be adjusted in an optimal way. |
|
Robert Göx, Strategic transfer pricing, absorption costing and vertical integration, In: SSRN, No. 98661, 1998. (Working Paper)
 
This paper analyzes the use of transfer pricing as a strategic device in divisionalized firms facing duopolistic price competition. When transfer prices are observable, both firms' headquarters will exclude their marketing division from the external input market and charge a transfer price above the market price of the intermediate product to induce their marketing managers to behave as softer competitors on the final product market. When transfer prices are not observable, strategic transfer pricing is not an equilibrium, and the optimal transfer price equals the market price of the intermediate product. As an alternative, the firms can signal their competitor a transfer price above the market price of the intermediate input through a proper choice of their accounting system. The paper identifies conditions under which the choice of absorption costing is a dominant strategy for both firms. Moreover, when the firms' products are close substitutes, the strategic benefits of full cost based transfer pricing can provide incentives to maintain a production department that would not be able to survive as a separate firm in the long run. |
|
Luke Lindsay, Chris Starmer, Steven Humphrey, Consumption experience, choice experience and the endowment effect, In: CeDEx discussion paper series, No. 16, 2012. (Working Paper)

This paper reports an experiment investigating how different kinds of experience influence the endowment effect. Previous studies have investigated how the endowment effect is influenced by experience gained through repetition of decision problems and trading in natural and experimental markets. In this study we explore how it is influenced by experience of consuming elements of a potential endowment and by experience of choosing prior to acquiring an endowment. We find evidence of an endowment effect and that measured loss aversion predicts the reluctance to trade. We find no effect of consumption experience. Choice experience increases trading. Finally, we find evidence of a new species of 'splitting effect', whereby acquiring an endowment in two instalments significantly reduces trading. |
|
Kremena Bachmann, Thorsten Hens, Investment competence and advice seeking, In: Department of Banking and Finance, No. 4499, 2013. (Working Paper)
 
This paper evaluates individuals’ ability to avoid investment mistakes and analyzes how investment competence is related to the propensity to seek or rely on professional advice. To address these issues, we use novel survey data collected from a representative sample of Swiss households. We find that investment competence is characterized by significant age and gender gaps, and that individuals who rely less on price movements as a source of information about investments are more likely to show above-the-average investment competence. We also find that individuals with relatively extensive investment experience and those who rely relatively strongly on their own judgment in making investment decisions are more likely to make investment decisions autonomously. In addition, we find that investment competence is positively related to the demand for financial advice. Thus, it appears that the individuals who most need financial advice are those who are least likely to seek such advice and rely on it. |
|
Stéphane Guérard, Ann Langley, Testing, contesting and legitimizing technology diffusion in regulated environments, In: UZH Business Working Paper Series, No. 301, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
Based on a longitudinal case study approach, this paper shows that the legitimation processes of technology diffusion in regulated environments is subjected to distinct power struggles manifested in different framing contests when several competing technological frames are crafted, are contradictory and attempt at capturing the same resources. We show that technology framing contests increase ambiguity which may in turn spark the need to rely on technology testing in order to bring a resolution of the debate, to lower ambiguity and to provide legitimacy to the purpose and benefits of a technology. Furthermore, we show that when framing contests over diffusion cannot be resolved through legitimated means, institution testing may come into play. This is likely to occur when the cultural-cognitive legitimacy of a technology has acquired sufficient force to trump regulatory legitimacy. |
|
Christoph Bode, Robin Gustafsson, Stéphane Guérard, Framing contests and institutional change: the case of the automotive field and the environmental movement in Germany, In: UZH Business Working Paper Series, No. 302, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
Based on an in-depth case study, this paper examines how framing contests between proponents and opponents of the Diesel particulate filter (DPF) in Germany evolve over time to affect institution creation. Our results suggest that the emergence of institution passes through three cumulative phases: necessary opening, organizing-mobilizing, instrumentalization of channels. This development is characterized by specific framing contests where the precedent phase is a necessary condition for the next to occur, a process which we conceptualize as cumulation. Our data indicate that framing contests were resolved when collective action frames which have a motivational task were crafted by the social movement with the effect of mobilizing customers, thereby creating a de facto standard i.e. the Diesel particulate filter. We argue that the motivational frame resonated because it features negative individualized evidence-based consequences and because it built on the framing contests of previous phases. Finally, we observed that framing contests tend to polarize over time, thereby reflecting the intensity of the conflict. |
|
Andreas Scherer, Guido Palazzo, David Seidl, Managing legitimacy in complex and heterogeneous environments: sustainable development in a globalized world, In: UZH Business Working Paper Series, No. 306, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
The sustainability problems of the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services increasingly challenges the legitimacy of corporations. Corporate legitimacy, however, is vital to the survival of corporations in competitive environments. The literature distinguishes three strategies that corporations commonly employ to address legitimacy problems: adapt to external expectations, try to manipulate the perception of their stakeholders or engage in a discourse with those who question their legitimacy. This paper develops a theoretical framework for the application of different legitimacy strategies and suggests that corporations facing sustainability problems have to be able to activate all three legitimacy strategies, despite their inherent incompatibilities. |
|
Donald MacLean, Robert MacIntosh, David Seidl, Thinking inside the box: linking dynamic capabilities to theories of action, In: UZH Business Working Paper Series, No. 310, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
We argue that development of dynamic capabilities theory into a fully dynamic theory of strategy is inhibited by the operation of an incomplete set of perspectives on human action. Clarifying how human action is conceptualized, particularly as regards creativity and learning, might help strategy scholars to develop theory in ways that adequately address action at all levels of engagement in dynamic contexts, thereby turning existing contradictions into complementarities whilst accounting for issues of both content and process. By reorganizing existing literatures along action theoretic lines the paper reframes some of the difficulties in current theorizing, illustrates the value of this reframing by applying action theory to recent work on dynamic capabilities and proposes a rules-based framework as a potential integrating device for the field. The paper closes by highlighting the need for interdisciplinary research in strategy. |
|
Dominik van Aaken, Clemens Koob, Katja Rost, David Seidl, Ausgestaltung und Erfolg von Strategieworkshops: Eine empirische Analyse (Forms and Success of Strategy Workshops: An Empirical Study), In: UZH Business Working Paper Series, No. 311, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
Despite their pervasiveness in organizational life, their associated costs and time investments, strategy workshops have received comparatively little attention by management researchers in the past. In this quantitative-empirical study, we examine for the first time systematically the different forms of strategy workshops and their respective effects. The study is based on a survey among 639 managers from different industries in Germany. We identified several factors as crucial for the success of strategy workshops. Keywords: strategy workshops, strategy development, strategy implementation, strategy as practice. |
|
Helmut Max Dietl, Markus Lang, Eric Lucas, Dirk Martignoni, Learning through inaccurate replication, In: UZH Business Working Paper Series, No. 312, 2012. (Working Paper)
 
Replicating a successful “template” or best practice across time (“temporal replication”) or across a number of different economic settings (“spatial replication”) is an important strategy for organizational growth and performance improvement. In this paper, we use an NK landscape model to examine how organizations may innovate and adapt to their environment through “inaccurate replication”. We identify conditions under which inaccurate replication can result in higher long-run performance than accurate replication. We also uncover the specific mechanisms through which replication errors may affect organizational performance. In that, our study also sheds a new light on how organizations may learn from (replication) errors. |
|