Manuel Oechslin, Creditor Protection and the Dynamics of the Distribution in Oligarchic Societies, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 264, 2006. (Working Paper)
"This paper introduces credit market imperfections and barriers to entrepreneurship into the Ramsey growth model. It is assumed that only a small elite, the oligarchs, may run firms and that these oligarchs – when borrowing from workers – may renege on the debt contracts at low cost. In such an economy, poor contract enforcement slows down the transition towards the steady state and alters the dynamics of the distribution strongly in favour of the oligarchs. The reason is that the workers are forced to charge “low” borrowing rates in order to decrease the incumbents’ incentives to default. With dynastic preferences, low returns reduce the workers’ propensity to save; they discount future wages less and consume more out of current income. Calibrations of the model suggest that the elite’s welfare gains are large – even if the oligarchic structure were associated with substantially lower productivity growth rates. These findings point to political forces behind low financial development." |
|
Thorsten Hens, Martin Vlcek, Does Prospect Theory Explain the Disposition Effect?, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 262, 2006. (Working Paper)
The disposition effect is the observation that investors hold winning stocks too long and sell losing stocks too early. A standard explanation of the disposition effect refers to prospect theory and in particular to the asymmetric risk aversion according to which investors are risk averse when faced with gains and risk-seeking when faced withnlosses. We show that for reasonable parameter values the disposition effect can however not be explained by prospect theory as proposed by Kahneman and Tversky. The reason is that those investors who sell winning stocks and hold loosing assets would in the first place notnhave invested in stocks. That is to say the standard prospect theory argument is sound ex-post, assuming that the investment has takennplace, but not ex-ante, requiring that the investment is made in the first place. |
|
Reto Foellmi, Manuel Oechslin, Equity and Efficiency under Imperfect Credit Markets, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 265, 2006. (Working Paper)
Recent macroeconomic research discusses credit market imperfections as a key channel through which inequality retards growth. Limited borrowing prevents the less affluent individuals from investing the efficient amount, and the inefficiencies are considered to become stronger as inequality rises. This paper, though, argues that higher inequality may actually boost aggregate output even with convex technologies and limited borrowing. Less equality in the middle or at the top end of the distribution is associated with a lower borrowing rate and hence better access to credit for the poor. We find, however, that rising relative poverty is unambiguously bad for economic performance. Hence, we suggest that future empirical work on the inequality-growth nexus should use more specific measures of inequality rather than measures of “overall” inequality such as the Gini index. |
|
Urs Fischbacher, Simon Gächter, Heterogeneous social preferences and the dynamics of free riding in public goods, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 261, 2006. (Working Paper)
"We provide a direct test of the role of social preferences in voluntary cooperation. We elicit individuals’ cooperation preference in one experiment and make a point prediction about the contribution to a repeated public good. This allows for a novel test as to whether there are ""types"" of players who behave consistently with their elicited preferences. We find clear-cut evidence for the existence of ""types"". People who express free rider preferences show the most systematic deviation from the predicted contributions, because they contribute in the first half of the experiment. We also show that the interaction of heterogeneous types explains a large part of the dynamics of free riding. " |
|
Dominic Rohner, Anna Winestein, Bruno Frey, Ich Bin Auch ein Lemming: Herding and Consumption Capital in Arts and Culture, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 270, 2006. (Working Paper)
Trends in arts and culture tend to be longer-lasting and less fragile than in other fields such as clothing design. Most herding models are not able to explain such stability, instead predicting informational cascades to be fragile and fads to be frequent. Thenpresent contribution is able to explain the hysterisis of trends in arts by incorporating thenaccumulation of consumption capital into a herding model. Further, the model is testednempirically by analyzing measures of relative and absolute concentration in the television business. It is concluded that by being exposed to art and culture people accumulate consumption capital for a particular style or artist and that this mechanism tends to make herding in arts stable over time. |
|
Manuel Oechslin, Reto Foellmi, Market Imperfections, Wealth Inequality, and the Distribution of Trade Gains, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 266, 2006. (Working Paper)
We explore the role of the ownership structure of capital in an economy that suffers from barriers to entry and an imperfect financial system. In such an environment, an unequal distribution of capital provides an explanation for trade flows and trade gains even when countries do not differ in relative factor endowments or available technologies. Moreover, an uneven asset distribution is associated with a large import-competing sector and only a small number of export-oriented entrepreneurs. Along these lines, we suggest that an unequal asset distribution may be key to understand why still many less developed countries protect their firms from foreign competition. |
|
Benno Torgler, Sascha L Schmidt, Bruno Frey, Relative Income Position And Performance: An Empirical Panel Analysis, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 268, 2006. (Working Paper)
Many studies have established that people care a great deal about their relative economic position and not solely, as standard economic theory assumes, about their absolute economic position. However, behavioral evidence is rare. This paper provides an empirical analysis on how individuals’ relative income position affectsntheir performance. Using a unique data set for 1114 soccer players over a period ofneight seasons (2833 observations), our analysis suggests that the larger the income differences within a team, the worse the performance of the soccer players is. Thenmore the players are integrated in a particular social environment (their team), thenmore evident this negative effect is. |
|
Michael Wolf, Resampling vs. Shrinkage for Benchmarked Managers, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 263, 2006. (Working Paper)
A well-known pitfall of Markowitz (1952) portfolio optimization is that the sample covariance matrix, which is a critical input, is very erroneous when there are many assets to choose from. Ifnunchecked, this phenomenon skews the optimizer towards extreme weights that tend to performnpoorly in the real world. One solution that has been proposed is to shrink the sample covariance matrix by pulling its most extreme elements towards more moderate values. An alternative solution is the resampled efficiency suggested by Michaud (1998). This paper compares shrinkagenestimation to resampled e*ciency. In addition, it studies whether the two techniques can bencombined to achieve a further improvement. All this is done in the context of an active port-nfolio manager who aims to outperform a benchmark index and who is evaluated by his realizedninformation ratio. |
|
Alois Stutzer, Bruno Frey, What Happiness Research Can Tell Us About Self-Control Problems And Utility Misprediction, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 267, 2006. (Working Paper)
Neoclassical economic theory rules out systematic errors in consumption choice. According to the basic view, individuals know what they choose. They are able to predict how much utility an activity or a good produces for them now and in the future and they can maximize their utility. This implies that behavior reveals consistent preferences. This approach makes it impossible to detect and understand sub-optimal consumption decisions, due to problems of self-control and thenmisprediction of utility. We propose the economics of happiness as a methodologicalnapproach to study these phenomena. Based on proxy measures for experiencednutility, it is, in principle, possible to directly address whether some observed behaviornis sub-optimal and is therefore reducing a person’s well-being. We discuss recent evidence on smoking and eating habits, TV viewing and commuting choice. |
|
Salvador Barberà, Anke Gerber, A Note on the Impossibility of a Satisfactory Concept of Stability for Coalition Formation Games, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 238, 2005. (Working Paper)
In this note we show that no solution to coalition formation games can satisfy a set of axioms that we propose as reasonable. Our result points out that “solutions” to the coalition formation cannot be interpreted as predictions of what would be “resting points” for a game in the way stable coalition structures are usually interpreted. |
|
David Afshartous, Michael Wolf, Avoiding Data Snooping in Multilevel and Mixed Effects Models, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 260, 2005. (Working Paper)
"Multilevel or mixed effects models are commonly applied to hierarchical data; for example,nsee Goldstein (2003), Raudenbush and Bryk (2002), and Laird and Ware (1982). Although therenexist many outputs from such an analysis, the level-2 residuals, otherwise known as randomneffects, are often of both substantive and diagnostic interest. Substantively, they are frequently used for institutional comparisons or rankings. Diagnostically, they are used to assess the modelnassumptions at the group level. Current inference on the level-2 residuals, however, typicallyndoes not account for data snooping, that is, for the harmful effects of carrying out a multitude of hypothesis tests at the same time. We provide a very general framework that encompasses both of the following inference problems: (1) Inference on the `absolute' level-2 residuals tondetermine which are significantly different from zero, and (2) Inference on any prespecified number of pairwise comparisons. Thus, the user has the choice of testing the comparisons of interest. As our methods are flexible with respect to the estimation method invoked, the user may choose the desired estimation method accordingly. We demonstrate the methods with the London Education Authority data used by Rasbash et al. (2004), the Wafer data used by Pinheiro and Bates (2000), and the NELS data used by Afshartous and de Leeuw (2004)." |
|
Joseph P Romano, Azeem M Shaikh, Michael Wolf, Formalized Data Snooping Based on Generalized Error Rates, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 259, 2005. (Working Paper)
It is common in econometric applications that several hypothesis tests are carried out at the same time. The problem then becomes how to decide whichnhypotheses to reject, accounting for the multitude of tests.nThe classical approach is to control the familywise error rate (FWE), that is, thenprobability of one or more false rejections. But when thennumber of hypotheses under consideration is large, control of the FWE can become too demanding. As a result, the number of false hypotheses rejected may be small or even zero. This suggests replacingncontrol of the FWE by a more liberal measure. To this end,nwe review a number of proposals from the statistical literature.nWe briefly discuss how these procedures apply to the general problem of model selection. A simulation study and two empirical applications illustrate the methods. |
|
Karolin Becker, Peter Zweifel, Cost Sharing in Health Insurance: An Instrument for Risk Selection?, In: Working paper series / Socioeconomic Institute, No. No. 513, 2005. (Working Paper)
Health insurance is potentially subject to risk selection, i.e. adverse selection on the part of consumers and cream skimming on the part of insurers. Adverse selection models predict that competitive health insurers can eschew high-risk individuals by offering contracts with low deductibles or co-payment rates, while attracting low-risk individuals with higher copayments, resulting in a separating equilibrium. This contribution seeks to determine whether in competitive Swiss social health insurance policies with deductibles in excess of the legal minimum do indeed serve as an instrument of risk selection. In a discrete choice experiment, effected in 2003, some 1,000 individuals were given the hypothetical choice of alternative insurance contracts that differed both in terms of deductibles and copayments and in bene.ts covered. Results suggest that healthy individuals, i.e. those not having consulted medical services during the past six months, were more likely to select a policy with a high deductible. Compensation demanded for voluntarily accepting an increase in the annual deductible also varies with socioeconomic characteristics and increases with the current level of deductible, as predicted by theory and constituting evidence in favor of the risk selection hypothesis. The experiment allows to compute necessary premium reductions and provides guidance for the pricing policy of insurers when offering differentiated products. |
|
Stefan Boes, Markus Lipp, Rainer Winkelmann, Money Illusion Under Test, In: Working paper series / Socioeconomic Institute, No. No. 514, 2005. (Working Paper)
Much progress has been made in recent years in developing and applying a direct measure of utility using survey questions on satisfaction with income and with life in general. In this paper we apply this new type of measurement to the study of money illusion. Using data from the German Socio-Economic Panel for the years 1993 to 2003, we cannot reject the hypothesis of no money illusion. |
|
Bruno Frey, Dominic Rohner, Protecting Cultural Monuments Against Terrorism, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 257, 2005. (Working Paper)
Famous cultural monuments are often regarded as unique icons, making them an attractive target for terrorists. Despite huge military and police outlays, terrorist attacks on important monuments can hardly be avoided. We argue that an effective strategy for discouraging terrorist attacks on iconic monuments is for the government to show a firm commitment to swift reconstruction. Using a simple game-theoretic model, we demonstrate how a credible claim to rebuild any cultural monuments destroyed discourages terrorist attacks by altering the terrorists’ expectations and by increasing the government’s reputation costs if they fail to rebuild. |
|
Bruno Frey, Zwei Utopien jenseits des Weltstaates und der Anarchie, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 258, 2005. (Working Paper)
"To overcome problems produced by globalization, some people see the solution in a WorldnGovernment while others see it in an autarchic global market without any governmentnintervention. Both solutions are rejected due to their major shortcomings. Two superiornsolutions are proposed: (1) A net of Functional, Overlapping Democratic Jurisdictions (FOCJ)nconfirming to a geography of problems; (2) The free choice of individuals to become citizensnnot only simultaneously in various nations but also in semi-public, non-governmental and private organizations as well as in private firms. The advantages and disadvantages of these proposals are discussed." |
|
Bruno Frey, Susanne Neckermann, Auszeichnungen: Ein Vernachlässigter Anreiz, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 254, 2005. (Working Paper)
Laut ökonomischer Standardtheorie sollen Arbeitsanreize mittels Geldzahlungen vermittelt werden. Materielle Anreize in nicht-monetärer Form sind demgegenüber weniger effizient, sind aber dennoch weit verbreitet. Auszeichnungen in Form von Titeln, Orden, Medaillen und Ehrungen (Preisen) wurden bisher nicht beachtet. Es handelt sich dabei um extrinsische, nicht-materielle Anreize die ihre Wirkung über den Urtrieb der Individuen nach sozialer Anerkennung und Status entfalten. Wir analysieren wie sich monetäre Anreize und Auszeichnungen unterscheiden: Auszeichnungen sind in der Regel billig, begründen soziale Beziehungen, sind nicht direkt mit der Leistung verknüpft und verfügen über eine Signalwirkung. Darüber hinaus unterstützen Auszeichnungen die intrinsische Motivation, können die Wohlfahrt erhöhen und sind steuerfrei. Auszeichnungen sind ein wichtiges zusätzliches Instrument im Arsenal der Prinzipal-Agenten-Theorie. In vielen Kontexten wirken sie besser als Geld. |
|
Stefan Buehler, Dennis Gärtner, Daniel Halbheer, Deregulating Network Industries: Dealing with Price-Quality Tradeoffs, In: Working paper series / Socioeconomic Institute, No. No. 402, 2005. (Working Paper)
This paper examines the effects of introducing competition into monopolized network industries on prices and infrastructure quality. Analyzing a model with reduced-form demand, we first show that deregulating an integrated monopoly cannot simultaneously decrease the retail price and increase infrastructure quality. Second, we derive conditions under which reducing both retail price and infrastructure quality relative to the integrated monopoly outcome increases welfare. Third, we argue that restructuring and setting very low access charges may yield welfare losses, as infrastructure investment is undermined. We provide an extensive analysis of the linear demand model and discuss policy implications. |
|
Daniel Waldenström, Bruno Frey, Did Nordic Countries Recognize the Gathering Storm of World War II? Evidence from the Bond Markets, In: Working paper series / Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, No. No. 336, 2005. (Working Paper)
This paper analyzes and compares different ways of assessing how people perceived impending threats of war in the past. Conventional Nordic historiography of World War IInclaims there were few, if any, people in the Nordic countries who perceived a significantlynincreased threat of war between 1938 and early 1940. At the same time, historical methodsnface problems when it comes to capturing the often tacitly held beliefs of a large numbernof people in the past. In this paper, we analyze these assessments by looking at suddennshifts in sovereign debt yields and spreads in the Nordic bond markets at that time. Ournresults suggest that Nordic contemporaries indeed perceived significant war risk increasesnaround the time of major war-related geopolitical events. While these findings questionnsome – but not all – of standard Nordic World War II historiography, they also demonstrate the value of analyzing historical market prices to reassess the often tacitly held views and opinions of large groups of people in the past. |
|
Philippe Mahler, Rainer Winkelmann, Secondary School Track Selection of Single - Parent Children Evidence from the German Socio-Economic Panel, In: Working paper series / Socioeconomic Institute, No. No. 415, 2005. (Working Paper)
In present day Germany, one in seven children is raised in a single parent household. We investigate the effect of single parenthood on children’s educational attainment, measured by the school track at the age 14, using ordered probit models. We study whether the effect of living in single parenthood during early or late childhood differs. Finally, we ask whether the family effect operates through resources – fewer income and parental time available for the child –, or through adverse effects on psychological well-being. The data used in this study are a nationally representative sample of 14 year old children drawn from the German Socio-Economic Panel. |
|